09/09/2020

The Fed risks higher inflation to boost jobs

Share on linkedin
Chalk logo

Introduction

The US central bank’s new monetary framework takes policy back to the 1960s

The new framework for US monetary policy announced at the Jackson Hole symposium in August is a watershed event, for both the practice of macroeconomic policy, and the theory that lies behind it.

With markets beginning to doubt whether the Federal Reserve can raise inflation to its 2 per cent target, the Federal Open Market Committee has become extremely concerned that it could lose control of inflation expectations, a fate that has already befallen the Bank of Japan and the European Central Bank. The new framework is best interpreted as a last-ditch attempt to avoid this outcome.

It shifts to an average inflation target — which will limit the danger of persistent undershooting of the 2 per cent objective, places maximum employment first among the Fed’s objectives, and abandons any mention of a “balanced” approach to policy.

In the sweep of economic history, this is a very important change. In the Federal Reserve Reform Act of 1977, following a period of “stagflation”, the US Congress gave the Fed three main objectives: maximum employment, stable prices and moderate long-term interest rates, in that order.

In the early 1980s, Paul Volcker crucially interpreted that mandate to place the greatest emphasis on stable prices. He broke the back of double-digit inflation but at the expense of increasing unemployment to above 10 per cent, the highest since the Depression.

By winning the political and intellectual battle for low inflation, Volcker established that the Fed had wide discretion to interpret its 1977 mandate. In 2012, Ben Bernanke’s statement of policy strategy translated the “stable prices” objective formally into a 2 per cent inflation target, which remained paramount in the 2010s.

The objective of maximum employment was now given a minor role in a “balanced” approach to monetary policy, in which the FOMC would seek to mitigate deviations of inflation from its target, and of employment from its undefined maximum level.

Adam Posen of the Peterson Institute is not alone in arguing that this approach has placed far too much emphasis on the need for pre-emptive tightening to control inflation. For example, the increases in interest rates in 2015-18 occurred when there was no major sign of above-target inflation. Even before the pandemic caused a surge in unemployment, this monetary tightening looked misjudged.

Although President Donald Trump’s criticisms of these interest rate decisions has been somewhat vindicated, the FOMC has not been influenced by political pressure in designing the new framework. As Fed chairman Jay Powell and vice-chair Richard Clarida have emphasised, the changes have been motivated by a long period in which inflation has remained below target.

This has occurred when equilibrium real interest rates have fallen to almost zero, leaving very little scope to ease conventional monetary policy in response to a future recession.

The shift to an average inflation target is a useful innovation. But more important is the promotion of the employment objective. Under the 2012 strategy, maximum employment was intended to refer to the natural rate of unemployment that would be consistent with stable inflation in the long run.

Now, maximum employment will be defined more literally, as the greatest utilisation of the labour force that can be attained with the economy working at full capacity. The FOMC’s main aim will be to attain this outcome at all times, unless the average inflation target is severely threatened.

This is similar to the old Keynesian framework of the 1960s, which required monetary and fiscal policy to seek to achieve “full” employment at a time when a strong economy did not appear to be inconsistent with stable prices.

William Martin, Fed chairman in the 1950s and ’60s, believed — like Mr Powell — in a generally low inflation rate, and on occasions raised interest rates to stabilise prices. But he was overtaken by the intellectual zeitgeist. At the end of his term, with inflation pressures clearly rising towards the highs seen in the next decade, he admitted defeat.

Given the persistent contractionary demand shocks triggered by the pandemic, and the deflationary episodes recently experienced in Japan and the EU, the Fed is justified in deciding to risk higher inflation for the immediate future.

But it is worth remembering that this regime eventually triggered the great inflation of five decades ago.

Source: This note is based on material which appeared in an article by Gavyn Davies published in the Financial Times on 6 September 2020.
This material is for your information only and is not intended to be used by anyone other than you. It is directed at professional clients and eligible counterparties only and is not intended for retail clients. The information contained herein should not be regarded as an offer to sell or as a solicitation of an offer to buy any financial products, including an interest in a fund, or an official confirmation of any transaction. Any such offer or solicitation will be made to qualified investors only by means of an offering memorandum and related subscription agreement. The material is intended only to facilitate your discussions with Fulcrum Asset Management as to the opportunities available to our clients. The given material is subject to change and, although based upon information which we consider reliable, it is not guaranteed as to accuracy or completeness and it should not be relied upon as such. The material is not intended to be used as a general guide to investing, or as a source of any specific investment recommendations, and makes no implied or express recommendations concerning the manner in which any client’s account should or would be handled, as appropriate investment strategies depend upon client’s investment objectives. Funds managed by Fulcrum Asset Management LLP are in general managed using quantitative models though, where this is the case, Fulcrum Asset Management LLP can and do make discretionary decisions on a frequent basis and reserves the right to do so at any point. Past performance is not a guide to future performance. Future returns are not guaranteed and a loss of principal may occur. Fulcrum Asset Management LLP is authorised and regulated by the Financial Conduct Authority of the United Kingdom (No: 230683) and incorporated as a Limited Liability Partnership in England and Wales (No: OC306401) with its registered office at Marble Arch House, 66 Seymour Street, London, W1H 5BT. Fulcrum Asset Management LP is a wholly owned subsidiary of Fulcrum Asset Management LLP incorporated in the State of Delaware, operating from 350 Park Avenue, 13th Floor New York, NY 10022.
©2020 Fulcrum Asset Management LLP. All rights reserved

About the Author

Gavyn Davies

Gavyn Davies is Chairman of Fulcrum Asset Management and co-founder of Active Partners and Anthos Capital. He was the head of the global economics department at Goldman Sachs from 1987-2001 and Chairman of the BBC from 2001-2004. He has also served as an economic policy adviser in No 10 Downing Street, and an external adviser to the British Treasury. He is a visiting fellow at Balliol College, Oxford.

Gavyn Davies
Your privacy

Cookies are data files that are stored on your computer or other smart device by a website’s server. Each cookie is unique to your web browser. It will contain some anonymous information such as a unique identifier, website’s domain name, and some digits and numbers. Cookies are useful as they allow us to recognise a user’s device and its preferences in order to ensure that our website works properly. By continuing to use this website, you consent to the use of our cookies.

 

You can find out the different types of cookies used on our website in our Cookies and Data Privacy Policies.

Necessary cookies